The Tribune - Spectrum

ART & LITERATURE
'ART AND SOUL
BOOKS
MUSINGS
TIME OFF
YOUR OPTION
ENTERTAINMENT
BOLLYWOOD BHELPURI
TELEVISION
WIDE ANGLE
FITNESS
GARDEN LIFE
NATURE
SUGAR 'N' SPICE
CONSUMER ALERT
TRAVEL
INTERACTIVE FEATURES
CAPTION CONTEST
FEEDBACK

Sunday,
October 5, 2003
Books

IMF’s learning at nations’ cost
G.V. Gupta

Globalization and its Discontents
by Joseph Stiglitz. Penguin, New Delhi. Pages 282.
Rs 395.

THIS is a sharp attack on the "Washington Consensus" by established economist Joseph Stiglitz, a Noble laureate and former Chief Economist of the World Bank. Though Stiglitz is not against globalisation or free market, he has challenged the ‘fundamentalist’ outlook of the IMF and the US Treasury for their ‘one size fits all’ treatment of individual economies. The treatment is simple: one dose, and fast—stabilise, liberalise and privatise without prioritising or watching for side effects. It is immaterial whether the countries concerned are small economies of the Sub-Saharan Africa or the fast-growing ones of Southeast Asia struck by a temporary liquidity-cum-exchange crisis. Structural reform is the watchword, irrespective of its impact on employment or income. The consequences of this have been varied, depending upon the resistance offered. The best pupils—Indonesia, the Czech Republic and Argentina—suffered the most. On the other hand, China suffered the least.

Stiglitz saw it in the World Bank. In Ethiopia, the IMF objected to a premature repayment of a high-interest loan because it was not consulted beforehand. The IMF wanted Bosnia, a very small economy, to split its sole bank into four to create competition, overlooking the question of sustainability.

 


The worst treatment was reserved for transition and East Asian economies. The latter had continuously boomed for 15 years to be called ‘Asian Tigers.’ However, they too lately suffered from high fiscal deficit, adverse balance of payment, high inflation, ballooning real estate investment and questionable loans funded by high-interest, short-term external debt. These economies had low productivity but high consumption levels. In 1997, there was negative external balance of about 90 billion dollars due to the withdrawal of short-term funds and flight of capital. Currency values fell sharply by 40 per cent and more. Exports fell and the prices rose. Businesses closed, leading to high unemployment. An attempt to sustain the value of currency led to a heavy rush on the reserves. On request, the IMF organised external assistance of about $80 billion with strict conditions. Interest rates were raised, sharply going up to 40 per cent. Public expenditure was cut down, affecting social services. Privatisation of public enterprises was sought.

The author observes that while credit squeeze made high-debt enterprises bankrupt. Small enterprises failed for want of capital. Fast privatisation meant cheap acquisition of assets by foreigners. External assistance largely went to ease pressure on the banking system, i.e., the return of external debt. Capital adequacy norms were raised and banks were further squeezed of liquidity. Speculators gained in currency arbitrage and capital flew. The fall in the value of currency did not increase exports because there was nothing to export.

Stiglitz wanted a holding operation and sequenced reforms, use of external assistance to create liquidity, recall of external balances, moratorium on repayment of external debt, and withholding of bankruptcies as these were caused by macro policies and not due to productivity losses. Privatisation should have followed the creation of regulators, better disclosure norms and competition. The same applied to banks. The demand should have been maintained, and the fall in currency value should have been used to increase exports. He did not succeed.

He discounts the theory of capitalist conspiracy and blames it largely on arrogance, the lack of transparency and will to learn, a blind faith in theory and structural deficiencies of the IMF. Unlike the World Bank, IMF economists do not have deep understanding of individual economies. The IMF looks at the larger picture only and overemphasises budgetary and external balances. Its advisory and control mechanism is deeply influenced by the US Treasury as its largest shareholder.

The IMF was the brainchild of Keynes, a firm believer in state intervention to maintain full employment. He had seen economies suffering from temporary imbalances resorting to competitive devaluation to increase export, thereby causing international depression in the 30s. The IMF was designed to help maintain internal liquidity and demand in these economies by taking care of the temporary external imbalance. It is ironic that in economic crises of East Asia and Communist countries, the IMF played a role just the opposite of what Keynes would have wanted.

Fundamentalism is now discounted. The IMF recognises the success of India and China in controlled change. The need for structural change in the IMF to give greater weight to economies like India and China is recognised. However, one must also be aware that talk of proper sequencing and controlled change gives an opportunity to vested interests to slow down the reform process. India is the prime example. Stiglitz’s intervention has been timely. The book is a master’s work written in an easy style and priced reasonably.